Reading Time: 3 minutes (1,098 words)

CHAPTER I THE NATURE OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY

§ 1 a Contribution to the Critique of the Concept ‘Economic Activity’

Economic science began by examining money prices of goods and services. These inquiries evolved from studies of coinage and price movements. Early economists focused on specific problems rather than defining the concept of "economic activity" or its methods. They realized that the general economic principle, which applies to all rational actions, was not helpful in clearly distinguishing economic actions from non-economic ones. Additionally, the motivation behind actions cannot be divided into economic and non-economic without losing the unity of rational action. A complete theory of rational action must see it as a single concept.

§ 2 Rational Action

Rational action is driven by the desire for pleasure and the avoidance of pain, where pleasure includes everything people find desirable. There is no clear distinction between noble ethics and hedonism, as modern concepts encompass all human motives for action, whether moral or immoral. People act out of need and dissatisfaction because full happiness leads to inaction. Since resources are limited, individuals must prioritize their needs efficiently. Consequently, rational and economic actions are interconnected, as all actions are based on individual reasoning and desire.

§ 3 Economic Calculation

Economic activity involves making choices between different needs. People try to satisfy their most urgent needs first, which requires evaluating the value of the goods that can satisfy those needs. When deciding between simple options, such as whether to hunt or farm, it is easier to see the trade-offs. However, in more complex situations, like choosing between different energy sources, careful calculations are needed because the connections between actions and outcomes are not always clear.

For effective economic calculations, it is important to have a unit of measurement, but subjective use-value does not provide a clear unit. Instead, decisions often rely on the idea that some goods can be substituted for others. In an exchange economy, the objective exchange value of goods becomes the basis for calculations. This has several advantages, such as allowing people to see the value given by all individuals in trade, helping them compare various producers, and checking if a project can be profitable.

However, using money to calculate economic value has some limits. Money does not represent a fixed value and can fluctuate, which can affect both the prices of goods and the costs of production. While prices change, these short-term fluctuations usually do not make it impossible to calculate economic value.

One major limitation of money calculations is that they often do not take into account important factors that are hard to measure, like the beauty of a place or the health of a community. Although these aspects are not represented in money, they are still important and should be considered when making decisions.

While money calculations are crucial, they do not cover all valuable factors, especially those tied to personal feelings or significance. Choices based on value judgments are essential to economic activity, regardless of whether they can be directly translated into money.

For good economic calculations to happen, two main conditions are necessary: the ability to exchange higher-order goods and a working medium of exchange, like money. In simple situations, like within a household, evaluations can be made without money. However, as societies become more complex, systematic evaluations are required to guide decisions about what to produce and consume effectively.

In a more advanced economic society, lacking currency and free pricing makes rational economic management nearly impossible. If a socialist system tries to replace money calculations with direct evaluations of goods, it will face challenges, especially when assessing the production of complex goods that require systematic planning.

A socialist community may be able to recognize its resources and production needs, but it struggles to accurately determine how to use these resources. It can't measure the cost-effectiveness of different production processes, making it difficult to plan efficiently.

Without a system of monetary exchange, a socialist community may know what goods are needed but cannot figure out how to allocate resources or measure their value effectively. In a free-market economy, prices help reflect supply and demand, guiding resource allocation.

In a theoretical stationary society, where economic patterns stay the same, one might think a rational socialist economy could exist. However, this is purely theoretical. In reality, economies are always changing, and relying on past conditions is not feasible. The shift to socialism itself changes how resources are used and what people want, complicating the application of traditional economic calculations.

In short, socialism cannot use the necessary tools for economic calculation, which leads to a system where making rational economic decisions is very hard. Any changes to the economy would lead to unpredictable results, creating uncertainty that disrupts the principles of a rational economy.

§ 4 the Capitalist Economy

"Capitalism" and "Capitalistic Production" are terms created by socialists to criticize the economic system and highlight the exploitation of workers by the rich. These terms are often unclear and lead to different opinions about their meaning. In business, capital refers to property values measured in money, used for calculations to see how these values change. When production is based on capital calculations, the term capitalism becomes clear and can be compared to socialism, not individualism. This way of looking at capitalism shows how large businesses develop due to these calculations, helping us understand the concepts without confusion about individual and societal interests.

§ 5 the Narrower Concept of the ‘Economic’

Economists often try to separate "economic" actions from "non-economic" ones, but this distinction is problematic. All human actions are connected, and people often face conflicts between different desires. The satisfaction of both material and ideal needs should be evaluated using the same standard. In life, choices like between bread and honor or love and money are all subjected to the same evaluation process.

Economic activity is fundamentally rational and cannot be isolated from other human actions. It involves assessing ends and determining the best means to achieve them. Economic principles apply to all actions, although distinguishing between "purely economic" and other actions can be useful for analysis. This distinction highlights a specific goal—maximizing products measured in money— but it varies depending on an individual's values.

The "purely economic" sphere focuses on money calculation, but all actions ultimately serve the singular purpose of achieving satisfaction, which encompasses a variety of human wants. While satisfaction is subjective, similarities in needs and desires across society allow for social cohesion.

Therefore, the traditional divide between economic and non-economic motives fails since economic activities are linked to overall rationality. However, recognizing "purely economic" activities is still important since those can be accurately valued in monetary terms. For example, decisions like going to war can be seen as rational if the perceived benefits outweigh the sacrifices, emphasizing the need for clear distinctions in evaluating actions.